Intertemporal discoordination in the 100% reserve banking system

Authors

  • Romain Baeriswyl Swiss National Bank

DOI:

https://doi.org/10.52195/pm.v12i2.136

Abstract

The 100%-Money plan advocated by Fisher (1936) has a Misesian flavor as it aims at mitigating intertemporal discoordination by reducing (i) the discrepancy between investment and voluntary savings, and (ii) the manipula­ tion of interest rates by monetary injections. Recent proposals to adopt the 100% reserve banking system, such as the Chicago Plan Revisited by Benes and Kumhof (2013) or the Limited Purpose Banking by Kotlikoff (2010), take, however, a fundamentally different attitude towards the role of the central bank in the credit market and ignore that intertemporal discoordination arises inde­ pendently from whether the credit expansion is financed by the creation of outside or inside money. These plans allow the central bank to inject outside money into the credit market and to effectively lower interest rates in negative territory in order to overcome the limit that the liquidity trap sets to credit expan­ sion in the fractional reserve system. Although such an attempt may succeed in stimulating the economy in the short run, it exacerbates intertemporal discoor­ dination and weakens economic stability in the long run.

Key words: monetary systems, 100% reserve banking, Chicago Plan, Austrian Business Cycle Theory.

JEL Classification: E30, E42, E58, B53.

Resumen: El plan «dinero 100%» defendido por Fisher (1936) tiene connotacio­ nes misianas en el sentido en que tiene como objetivo mitigar la descoordinación intertemporal reduciendo (i) la diferencia entre la inversión y el ahorro voluntario y (ii) la manipulación de los tipos de interés a través de inyecciones de dinero. Las recientes propuestas para adoptar un sistema de coficiente de reservas ban­ carias del 100%, tales como el Chicago Plan Revisited de Benes y Kumhof (2013) o el Limited Purpose Banking de Kotlikoff (2010), toman, sin embargo, una actitud esencialmente diferente hacia el papel del banco central en el mercado de cré­ dito, e ignora que la descoordinación intertemporal surge independientemente de si la expansión crediticia se financia mediante la creación de dinero desde dentro (inside money) o fuera (outside money). Estos planes permiten al banco central inyectar dinero desde fuera en el mercado de crédito y reducir los tipos de interés de manera efectiva en valores negativos con el fin de superar el límite que establece la trampa de la liquidez a la expansión del crédito en el sistema de reserva fraccionaria. Aunque tal intento puede tener éxito a la hora de esti­ mular la economía en el corto plazo, acentúa la descoordinación intertemporal y debilita la estabilidad económica a largo plazo.

Palabras clave: Sistemas monetarios, banca de reserva del 100%, Plan Chica­ go, teoría austriaca del ciclo económico.

Clasificación JEL: E30, E42, E58, B53.

References

Admati, A. and Hellwig, M. (2013): The Bankers’ New Clothes: What’s Wrong with Banking and What to Do About It. Princeton Universi-ty Press, Princeton.

Angell, J. W. (1935): The 100 per cent reserve plan. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 50(1):1-35.

Atkeson, A. and Kehoe, P. J. (2004): Deflation and depression: Is there an empirical link? Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Report, (331).

Bagus, P. (2010): Austrian business cycle theory: Are 100 percent reserves sufficient to prevent a business cycle? Libertarian Pa-pers, 2(2):1-18.

— (2014): Austrian economics and new currency theory on 100% banking: A response to Huber. Procesos de Mercado: Revista Eu-ropea de Economia Politica, 11(1):105-136.

Bagus, P. and Howden, D. (2010a): Fractional reserve free banking: Some quibbles. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 13(4):29-55.

— (2010b): The term structure of savings, the yield curve, and ma-turity mismatching. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 13(3):64-85.

Benes, J. and Kumhof, M. (2013): The Chicago Plan Revisited. IMF mimeo.

Bernholz, P. (1993): The importance of Böhm-Bawerk’s theory of capital and interest from an historical perspective. History of Economic Ideas, 1(2):21-58.

Böhm-Bawerk, E. v. (1889): Capital and Interest: Positive Theory of Cap-ital. [Reprint by Libertarian Press, Pennsylvania, 1959], Vienna.

Bordo, M., Lane, J. L., and Redish, A. (2004): Good versus bad defla-tion: lessons from the gold standard era. NBER Working Paper Series, (10329).

Cantillon, R. (1755): Essai sur la nature du commerce en général. Fletcher Gyles, London.

Fisher, I. (1936): «100% Money». Adelphi Company, New York.

Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. (1963): A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Fullarton, J. (1844): On the regulation of currencies. John Murray, London.

Garrison, R. W. (2004): Overconsumption and forced saving in the Mises-Hayek theory of the business cycle. History of Political Economy, 36(2):323-349.

Hayek, F. A. (1935): Prices and Production. Augustus M. Kelly, New York.

— (1928): Intertemporal price equilibrium and movements in the value of money. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 28:33-76. [Reprint by Liberty Fund, Good Money, Part I, ed. Stephen Kresge, 1999]. Huber, J. (2011): Monetäre Modernisierung. Metropolis-Verlag, Marburg.

Huerta de Soto, J. (2009): Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles. 2nd Edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, US.

Kirzner, I. M. (1993): The pure time-preference theory of interest: An attempt at clarification. In Herbener, J. M., editor, The Meaning of Ludwig von Mises: Contributions in Economics, Sociology, Epistemology, and Political Philosophy. Ludwig von Mises Insti-tute, Auburn, Alabama, US.

Kotlikoff, L. J. (2010): Jimmy Stewart is Dead: Ending the World’s On-going Financial Plague with Limited Purpose Banking. Wiley, Ho-boken, New Jersey.

Lucas, R. E. J. (1972): Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4:103-124.

McLeay, M., Radia, A., and Thomas, R. (2014): Money creation in the modern economy. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin.

Menger, C. (1871): Principles of Economics. [Reprint by New York Universtiy Press,New York, 1976], Vienna.

Mises, L. v. (1912): The Theory of Money and Credit. [Reprint by Liber-ty Fund, Indianapolis, 1981], Vienna.

— (1949): Human Action. [Reprint by the Ludwig von Mises Insti-tute, Auburn, Alabama, 1998].

Phillips, C. A., McManus, T. F., and Nelson, R. W. (1937): Banking and Business Cycle. Arno Press, New York.

Rothbard, M. (1962): Man, Economy, and State. [Reprint by the Lud-wig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, US, 2009].

— (1963): America’s Great Depression. [Reprint by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, US, 2013].

Selgin, G. (1994): Free banking and monetary control. The Economic Journal, 104(427):1449-1459.

Simons, H. C. (1936): Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 44(1):1-30.

Wicksell, K. (1898): Interest and Prices. Macmillan, trans. Richard Kahn (1936), London.

Downloads

Published

2015-07-01

How to Cite

Baeriswyl, R. . (2015). Intertemporal discoordination in the 100% reserve banking system. REVISTA PROCESOS DE MERCADO, 12(2), 43–80. https://doi.org/10.52195/pm.v12i2.136

Issue

Section

Articles